Governance
in Greek higher education from a comparative perspective
Kiprianos Pandelis Politis-Stergiou
Vangelis
University of Patras
Technological Institution of West Greece
Introduction
After the 1980s, significant changes were noted in the
organization and governance of H.E. in many western countries. Generally speaking, from a shared model which
was predominant internationally but with national particularities, we moved to
a managerial model which is characterized by the withdrawal of the state, a
greater opening up to the market and a reduction in the participation of the
academic community. In Greek H.E. the
development is somewhat different. In
the 1980s when all the more countries were adopting elements of the managerial
model, in Greece the model of shared governance was introduced. However, over time, and especially in recent
years, more and more of the main principles of the managerial model are being
adopted.
Our objective in the present text is, based on texts
from international bodies and the relevant debates in Greece, to provide a
picture of this development and to evaluate the results so far of the changes
at the level of organization and governance of H.E. To do this we believe that
it is vital to view these changes through the comparative prism of two data. These
are reforms in H.E. internationally and the changes at the level of governance.
The comparative point of view will allow us to understand the relevant
developments in Greece as well as to better assess the results of these
developments.
Framework of the debate
From Immanuel Kant and on, debate on the University
endeavors to illuminate the objective of the institution and its relationship
with power, political power nowadays and religious power in the past. In the
aftermath of World War Two, a new dimension, partly connected to the first was
added to this problematic, that of the view of formal education and
particularly of the university, as a public good.
A fundamental principle of the Kantian perception of
the university and knowledge is the existence of a new school, seen until then
as inferior, which would have a dual role.
On the one hand it would compose the discourse of the other sciences
and, on the other, keep a check on the value of their discourse as well as the
discourse of power, without being accountable to the latter. In other words this school, of Philosophy, is
assigned the objective of the quest for truth through the cultivation of moral
Discourse (Kant 107-109).
The Kantian view will undergo change as far as the
central position of discourse is concerned, with the German Idealists at the
beginning of the 19th century, who were behind the establishment of
the first modern university, of Berlin (1810), but it will not change in terms
of its rationale. The central category
in their discourse is the term culture.
As Bill Readings notes: ‘The process of hermeneutic reworking is called
culture, and it has a double articulation. On the one hand, culture names an identity. It is the unity of all knowledges that are
the object of study; it is the object of Wissenschaft
(scientific – philosophical study). On the other hand, culture names a process of development, of the
cultivation of character –Bildung. In
the modern University, the two branches of this process are research and
teaching, and the particularity of Idealists was to insist that the specificity
of the University comes from the fact that it is the place where the two are
inseparable. The high school practices teaching without research; the academy
practices research without teaching. The University is the center of the
educational system, because it is where teaching and research are combined, so
that in Schelling’s words, the ‘’nurseries of science’’ must also be
‘’institutions of general culture’ (Readings 1996: 64).
For many researchers these two considerations compose
the framework that should define even today the objective and the position of
the University in today’s societies, as well too as its relationship with every
kind of power, either political or economic.
This position is concentrated in the freedom of teaching and research as
Wilhelm von Humboldt codified it and which defines the relationship of the
institution with political power within the framework of the Nation-state.
The Kantian as much as the Humboldtian perception
continue today to inspire the views of important scholars on the University. The
demand is for the autonomy of the University and its non-subjection to reasoning
which cancels out its objective. This doesn’t necessarily mean that it should
be an institution cut off from the environment, both social and political, an
ivory tower. In contrast, it ought to diffuse these knowledge, truths and
values across all society, to make it a shareholder and to infuse it so that
society itself acts based on these principles.
After the Second World War, a new dimension was added
to the picture of the University. It
originates mainly in the Economic Sciences and is linked to the concept of
public good, which was chiefly worked on by Paul Samuelson. According to R.G. Holcombe “Economists define
a public good as a good having one of the characteristics of no excludability
and joistless in consumption. No excludability means that it is difficult to
keep people from consuming the good once it has been produced, and jointness in
consumption means that once it is produced for one person, additional consumers
can consume at no additional cost. Goods that are joint in consumption are also
called collective-consumption goods or non-rival consumption goods, and the
terms are used interchangeably here.
The most precise technical definition of a public
good, and the definition that is most often referred to by economics, is
Samuelson’s definition, which says that a public good is a good that, once
produced for some consumers, can be consumed by additional consumers at no
additional cost. This is the joistless in consumption referred to above”
(Holcombe 1997: 2).
We can of course ask ourselves whether these two
preconditions are valid in education and if the exclusive body responsible for
the provision of public goods is the public authorities. We know from the Sociology of Education that
not everyone has equal access to education, in other words, the right to
it. The second problem is with the body
responsible for the production and management of the public good. Can the public authorities, a priori, produce
and distribute public goods better? Can
private bodies respond to this mission? The
debate is composite and goes beyond the scope of the present text. In any case the discussions on H.E. can’t
ignore either the issue of autonomy or the view of education as a public good.
Contemporary
transformations in Higher Education
Over the years the universities have become all the
more composite institutions, a fact which changes as much the relationships
within them, as their relationships with the external environment. As far as inside the universities is
concerned, they are becoming more massified.
In a matter of a few decades, the number of students multiplied and the
number of teaching staff increased (Friedberg, Musselin 1989: 38). This resulted in a significant percentage of
young people, in western countries many more than half of them, registering in
higher education.
Equally important is the change in the relationships
between higher education and the external environment, mainly the market. From the Middle Ages until the beginning of
the 19th century, the universities were, on the whole, economically
independent. The authorities that
established them provided them with land, property or assets, which they
managed themselves (Gerbod: 84). Beyond
the assets and other resources, governance of the university is also crucial,
since they are self-governing.
Corporatist associations initially, of teachers or learners, managed to
govern themselves as collectives. From
this viewpoint, the role of the rector is significant as he has first say on
issues of governance, representation and organization of studies.
Things changed at the beginning of the 19th
century with the appearance of two main models of the university: the French,
which focused on the professional nature of studies, and the German
(humboldtian) which intended to dominate and to constitute the dominant
standard reference model. Since then and
until the 1970s, the universities were founded on two principles: public
funding and their autonomy.
The issue of the relationships between the State and
the public bodies on the one hand and the university on the other becomes more
composite from the end of the 19th century and even more so in
recent decades with the stronger link of the latter with the market. From then on one of the most fundamental
questions that is raised continually concerns the relationship between them and
consequently, the objectives of the University and the content of the produced
knowledge.
At the beginning of the 20th century Thorstein Veblen poses the question of the
relationships between the University and the market. He claims that the
University depends more and more on businessmen and functions as a business (1918:65). The debate on the matter in the
Western countries settled down in the post war period due to the generous
funding of higher education by the public authorities. As
Burton Clark notes: «The decade of 1958-1968, a period of relatively stable
prices, saw a sevenfold increase in
federal funds for basic university research (from $178 million to $1,251
million. The 1950s and especially the 1960s were a golden age for American
academic science” (1995: 130).
The
question reappears in the 1970s when many states, starting with the USA and
Great Britain, because of the economic crisis but also for ideological reasons,
have a precedent for reducing public spending. Since public funding is reduced
almost constantly, the higher education institutions are turning to the private
sector (OECD 2014: 232). The turn constitutes a significant moment in the
history of higher education, which is starting to change the balance between
autonomy/funding
Derek Bok puts the change down to the economic crisis
in 1973 and
the consequent need of the American universities to find other financial
sources. “This change in
priorities led the government to consider new ways of linking university
research to the needs of business. In
1980, Congress passed the Bay-Dole Act, which made it much easier for the
universities to own and license patents on discoveries made through research
paid for with public funds. Federal and
state legislation offered subsidies for a variety of university-cooperative
ventures to help translate the fruits of academic science into new products and
processes. Tax breaks encouraged
industry to invest more in university-based science” (Bok 2003: 11-12). In the
years that followed other countries too, like France, since 1999, have adopted
a similar policy.
Its massification as much as the change in its
relationships with the external environment have made higher education an all
the more composite institution. In 1964
Clark Kerr had already claimed that the university had radically changed and
been transformed into something new, more composite which he called
Multiversity: “The multiversity
is an inconsistent institution. It is not one community, but several – the community
of the undergraduate and the community of the graduate; the community of the
humanist, the community of the social scientist, and the community of the
scientist; the communities of the professional schools; the community of all
the non-academic personnel; the community of the administrators. Its edges are fuzzy-it reaches out to alumni,
legislators, farmers, businessmen, who are all related to one or more of these
internal communities” (Kerr
1964:18-9). Three decades later Burton
Clark too would make a similar claim. “In short, diversity, not uniformity, is
the master trend. The need to
concentrate and hence differentially distribute financial resources and
personnel and equipment and students grows ever stronger as higher education systems
grow in population size and in coverage of cognitive territories. The institutional division of labour can no
more be stopped, let alone reversed, than the division of labour in society. Hence the thought that all institutions of
higher education can be equal becomes a species of utopianism. If differentiation is not effected among
institutions, it will take place within them, producing ever more polyglot
universities that call for heroic internal management to simply maintain
peaceful relations among disparate factions and somehow insert a capacity for
spontaneous change” (Clark 1995: 246).
On
governance: From the shared to a new managerial model
From their very beginnings, the universities were
self-governed. The constituents of the
university participated in governance which means governance was shared.
According to Gary Olson “Shared governance is not a simple matter of committee
consensus, or the faculty's engaging administrators to take on the dirty work,
or any number of other common misconceptions. Shared governance is much more
complex; it is a delicate balance between faculty and staff participation in
planning and decision-making processes, on the one hand, and administrative
accountability on the other” (Olson 2009).
Undoubtedly, in the past governance wasn’t exactly
shared. Universities and professors were
dependent on various things (the church, political power, groups). On the other hand, power within the university
was never equally distributed. The professors, especially in the Germanic
universities, had more power than the other groups and played a decisive role
in decision making. However, amongst the
professors too, some had and continue to have more power than others (Ringer
1979).
Despite this, the universities were self-governing and
governance was exercised collectively.
This trend was strengthened in the 1960s and 1970s. In the USA in 1964
The American Association of University Professors adopted and published the
“Statement on government of colleges and universities”.[1] “Describing the essential
relationship” argues Robert Birnbaum, “between trustees, presidents and faculty
as based on ‘mutual understanding’ ‘joint effort’ and ‘inescapable
interdependence’, the Joint Statement laid out two basic principles of what has
come to be known as ‘shared governance’:
(1). Important areas of action involve at one time or
another the initiating capacity and decision-making participation of all the
institutional components, and (2) difference in the weight of each voice, from
one point to the next, should be determined by the reference to the
responsibility of each component for the particular matter at hand (…)
(Birnbaum 2003: 3).
The picture is similar in the European
universities. In France the student
uprising in 1968 changed the University.
It brought students and teachers closer together and had a catalytic
effect on the pedagogic relationship since more weight was assigned to the
student in the exchange too. With E.
Faure’s law in 1969 students participated actively at all levels of governance.
(Prost 1997: 150-152). As far as the
British universities are concerned, Moodie and Eustace wrote in 1974: “it is
indisputable that the century has witnessed a substantial move towards internal
academic self-governance in all major areas of decision making” (cited by
Lapworth 2004: 300).
The things then changed. The change is gradual and after the 1980s,
accelerates. This is reflected, among
other things, at a linguistic level.
“The term ‘management’, notes G. Lockwood, “was not part of the cultural
vocabulary of the university in 1945 except to describe a process or method of
organization alien to a public institution as opposed to a business firm. The
university was governed and administered but not managed. The history of the
internal organization and culture of the university since the war is reflected
in the gradual acceptance of the applicability of the term ‘management’ to the
processes of decision-implementation within the university. Broadly,
‘administration’ was the characteristic term until the early 1970s, with
‘governance’ having a phase of dominance in the late 1960s and again in the
1990s. ‘Management’ began to feature in the literature and conference papers in
the 1960s. Its acceptability and usage within the university came in the 1970s,
firstly as a reaction to the student-led wave of concentration upon the
politics of governance as the focus of internal organization in the late 1960s,
secondly under the impact upon universities of the oil-inflation-inspired world
economic crises of the mid-1970s” (Lockwood 2011: 124). Finally, the term
‘management’ began to be widely used after 1985 in parallel with the acceptance
and use of the term managerialism (Lockwood 2011:125). The change in language touches the people of
the university too. In the past we
talked more about an academic community, its members, its constituents. Today
we talk about stakeholders or consumers (Bolland 2005: 2009).
The changes in the terminology express the changing
ideological framework. Does all this
have any effect on the governance of higher education? In his well-known study, Burton Clark
distinguishes four types of university in terms of possession of power and the
exercise of governance: the continental mode (a combination of Faculty guild
and State bureaucracy) the British mode (a combination of Faculty guilds with a
modest amount of influence from institutional trustees and administrators), the
American Mode (“like the British has combined beloved faculty forms with
institutional leadership and administration but in comparison with the British
faculty rule has been weaker and the influence of trustees and administrators
stronger” and the Japanese mode (a mixture of the American and continental
mode) (Clark 1983: 125-130).
Since the publication of Clark’s typology, much has
changed. Tertiary education has been further massified, public funding has been
reduced. Its reduction led the universities into economic straights and pushed
them to seek funds from other sources. “According to McPerson et al.”, writes
J. Duderstadt, referring to the American Universities, “from 1990 to 2009
states have reduced their funding per enrolled student by an average of 35%,
totaling more than $15 billion each year nationally (Duderstadt 2014: 8). To
address the problem and its consequences concerning notably the future of the
American research universities the National Academy of Science and Engineering
and the Institute of Medicine have after a request made by Congress in 2010,
formed a committee made up of distinguished researchers. In 2012 the committee reached 10
recommendations. The second refers to funding.
“The states should strive to restore appropriations for higher education
to levels that allow public research universities to operate at world-class
levels, while providing them with greater autonomy to enable them to compete
strategically and respond with ability to new opportunities” (Duderstadt 2014:
8).
The changes are more dramatic in the countries in
continental Europe and generally in those with characteristics of the type
Clark called continental. In many of
these countries, especially in the south, and amongst them Greece, tertiary
education was heavily dependent on the State and had a comparatively small link
with the market. As a consequence, opening
up to the market is more painful since traditions and beliefs are put to the
test and relationships change which has an impact as much on the possession of
power as on governance and the practised policies (Kiprianos et al. 2011).
Did these changes lead to a new type of university
governance? Experts from seven
countries, six European and the USA who met in 1998 in Switzerland answered in
the affirmative. It is a new type of
governance called new managerialism. The
meeting’s coordinator, D. Braun distinguished, based on three criteria (belief
system, substantive rationality and procedural rationality) three types of
governance up to the 1980s. These were
the collegium model of the British universities, the market model of the USA
and the oligarchic-bureaucratic model, which characterizes European countries
such as France, Germany, Switzerland and Holland.
In the 1990s, Braun claims, things change with the
transition to a new managerialism type of governance which crystallizes into
two particular types: one, a more efficiency oriented model and a second
client/market oriented. The first mainly
characterizes countries which previously had the oligarchic-bureaucratic
model. The second, the USA, Great
Britain as well as Holland. The
transition to the first type comes about mainly through the search for
efficiency at a time of austerity. The
countries which are part of the second type are motivated by radical
utilitarian beliefs which are part of a wider neo-liberal strategy.
How do the two types differ? The second is distinguished by its greater
procedural freedom in decision making, it has less real autonomy from the
markets and finally strengthens the utilitarian value system. In short, the countries of the first type
come closer to those of the second but there are still differences in the
relationship with the state and the market and the value system. For Braun, this explains why the changes are
comparatively limited and less painful in the USA and a lot more painful in
other countries, particularly Great Britain which moved from one type, the
collective, to another, oriented to the client and the market (Braun, 1999:
239-261).
Governance in Greek HE
Up until 1982 governance in Greek HE brings to mind
Clark’s continental type and Braun’s corresponding oligarchic-bureaucratic
type. They are dependent on political
power and within them a numerically small group of full professors make the
decisions. Along general lines, however,
the oligarchic professors in Greece have less power than their opposite numbers
in countries with the same type of governance, like Germany, France and Italy,
and are more dependent on central power.
For this reason in the past in almost every signifying political event,
some professors are sacked and others hired.
An important moment for Greece came in 1982 with the
voting in of law 1268 by the PASOK government.
It aimed at the massification of H.E. (Kiprianos, 1995), the reduction
of its dependence on central power with the establishment of an executive,
‘intermediary’ body, the NCHE (National Council for Higher Education) and the
redistribution of the power relationships within it with the adoption of
institutions like the Department and the Sector in which all categories of
staff, mainly teaching and students, participated.
How is this particular law assessed as far as the
issue of governance of the University is concerned? After 2000 three important texts make
reference to the issue.
The first, the Eurydice network, responsible for the
European education network, evaluates law 1268 in positive terms. “On the whole, under the reforms introduced
to date, Greece has managed to apply the principle that the university decides
and the State supervises. Under the new
legislative framework that has been introduced, the role of the Ministry is
restricted to monitoring the legality of the procedures of the AEIs with
respect to the recruitment of teaching staff, while planning with regard to the
recruitment of administrative staff has been entrusted to the institutions
themselves. The Ministry, therefore, no
longer approves the study programs of the departments of the AEIs. The State now only handles general structural
matters and leaves the university and social bodies free to resolve more
specific problems” (Eurydice 2000: 270-1).
The second text is the introductory report of law
3549, voted on in 2007, which brought about changes, which were significant for
the structure and the governance of H. E. The existing legal framework is
criticised on two main grounds: its inefficiency and lack of transparency on
all levels. “A basic concern and widespread belief is that Greek Higher
Education is going through a deep and lasting crisis. The system of Higher Education is
characterized by centralization, introversion and lack of transparency. Within the folds of the H.E.I phenomena such
as a want of democracy in the choice and promotion of their administrative
staff, abuse of the concept of asylum and various dysfunctions are observed”.
(…) “Law 1268/1982 contains numerous imperfections and a number of clauses
which remain impossible to implement in practice. Its arrangements have been an object of
criticism from the academic community itself, and as a result today the
alteration of fundamental clauses and its conformity to international and
European data in the space of Higher Education, is considered absolutely
essential”.
Four years later, in 2011, the OECD report ‘Education
Policy Advice for Greece’ was published.
The report is quite different from the aforementioned report of 2000.
The following four issues are considered to be the main problems:
· The lack of capacity for effective institutional governance and management;
· Inefficient allocation of human and financial resources;
· Limited capacity to steer the system to achieve essential efficiencies and improved performance and to sustain the momentum of reform over changes in governments; and
· Limited non-public funding and cost-sharing to complement governmental subsidy. (OECD, 2011: 76).
The OECD makes recommendations, such as the fragmentation of a number of institutions, the existence of small-sized Departments and the overlap of cognitive subject areas by the universities and TEI. The report focuses mainly on two aspects: governance and the allocation of resources.
“From the perspectives of this OECD review, the key
provisions that must be in place for Greece to move forward include:
Strengthening of the governance and management
capacity of institutions to permit substantially increased devolution of
authority and responsibility from the ministry of education;
Establishing a new independent steering entity, the
Higher Education Authority, to provide overall co-ordination of the system and
to lead the step-by-step implementation of the reforms; and,
Undertaking fundamental reform of financial management
and the mechanisms for resource allocation and oversight”.
For governance, OECD suggests the institution of a
Council, which will have jurisdiction in all areas except the academic, which
will be taken on by the rector, who is appointed however by the former. “Governing
boards (Councils) must be of sufficient size to accommodate the necessary range
of interests and allow for the creation of specialist committees, such as a
subcommittee on finance (…). External members should constitute a majority of
the governing board. Ideally they should
be drawn from industry and the professions, not from the ranks of retired
academics. The latter will simply
perpetuate the current organisational culture.
HEIs need to involve external public interests and, with the prospect of
financial autonomy, these need to include financial expertise. The academic
community should welcome the creation of governing boards. The terms of membership of external members
should be sequenced to ensure continuity over time. Boards with frequent turnover of membership
have difficulty in maintaining the needed group cohesiveness for effective
governance and the core knowledge essential for addressing complex policy
issues (…). The chair of the governing
board should be drawn from the external members but should be elected from the
whole board” (OECD 2011: 82).
Shortly after the OECD report in 2011 law 4009
“Structure, function, quality assurance of studies and internationalization of
higher education institutions” was voted on in the Greek parliament. The law adopts many of the elements of the
OECD report but with some differentiations. The majority on the Council is held
by the internal members, the Rector is not appointed by the Council but elected
from a list of three candidates that the Council has chosen and approved.
How could these changes be perceived? They reflect those we drew attention to in
other western countries. The declared objective is efficiency in the face of
the debt crisis. With differences, however. If we look at Greek higher
education over time, we would say that it comprises a characteristic case of
the oligarchic-bureaucratic model. This
model weakens after 1982 with law 1268.
After 2007 attempts are made to rebuild the relationships between the
state and H.E. The basic tools for this are the four-year agreements between
the two sides based on particular objectives. The idea of the four-year
agreements is reproduced in law 4009/2011, but is not implemented. On the contrary, at a time of debt crisis,
two other matters are of interest. One
is the turn to a new mixed model with elements from both of D. Braun’s
types. It aims at efficiency within the
framework of the reduction of state funding and, at the same time, seeks
clients, students first and foremost.
Apart from the principles, the new model of governance
of the Greek H.E., as introduced by law 4009/2011, differs as much from OECD’s
recommendations as from certain principles of the Bologna Process. Private
interests, such as other public authorities, or employers’ associations are not
represented.
On the other hand, some steps are being taken in the
direction of the withdrawal of the state.
Arrangements are being introduced that give H.E. institutions the chance
to make contracts for the hiring of transport for the transportation of
students, cleaning contracts and contracts for the security and maintenance of
their facilities as well all other matters that relate to the particular needs
of each institution (article 5). The same reasoning is behind the policy
regarding the salaries for all categories of staff. Since they are paid directly by the state,
the objective is the reduction in the cost of salaries.
For the legitimization of these choices, the political
authorities need the support of the most influential professors. That is why
they had interest to increase their weight within their institutions. Hence we are being driven towards a model
where the state, through a part of the established professors controls the
operation of the university. This, however, is contrary to the idea that the
university should be self-governing. In
contrast, it leads to a perception that makes a distinction between efficiency
and democracy. According to this
reasoning, democracy is inefficient and has to be limited so that the
universities can respond to the challenges of the times (Kladis, 2012).
Concluding remarks
The policies on Greek H.E. originate in three
discourses. One which is seated in the dominance of the space of the Market.
The second is circumstantial and is linked to the transformations in the
University, its massification and the difficulties in its public funding. The
third refers to the current debt crisis in Greece and the problems this
produces.
These policies were put to the test during the years
of the crisis, and it seems they failed. They had extremely significant
consequences, which weigh down as much the operation of H.E. as the behaviours
of the members of the university community, staff and graduates.
The first consequence concerns the two previously cited principles of the University, in
other words its relationship with power and its consideration as a public
good. We saw that structural reform in
conjunction with ideological concerns lead to a perception that sees it as a
business, and sees students as clients.
This perception leads to a managerial model of governance, which aims at
efficiency ignoring its two main founding principles, as a public good and as a
space for the promotion of critical thought, in brief as a space for democracy
and the formation of active citizens.
On the other hand, these policies have consequences on
the funding of the HEIs and the staff. The
withdrawal of the state and the reduction in public funding took on new
dimensions during the crisis. Public
funding was dramatically reduced without being replaced by private funding and
enormous dysfunctions were created. This is vividly reflected in the decrease
in funding itself, the decrease in the number of staff and the decrease in
their salaries.
Undoubtedly public funding wasn’t reduced only in
Greece. According to the Commission’s report “Within the EHEA, all countries
except Luxembourg, France, Denmark and Germany decreased public expenditure for
tertiary education at a constant price at least once in the years between 2008
and 2012. (…) In a second group, yearly decrease(s) in public expenditure on
tertiary education were relatively small, and never exceeded 5% (…) In a third
group, countries experienced much more significant decreases (yearly decreases
higher than 5.5%) either during a single year (the United Kingdom, Portugal,
Latvia, the Czech Republic, Austria, Estonia, Ireland and Poland), over two
years (Bulgaria, Cyprus and Lithuania) or even over three years (Romania). In all these countries except Lithuania, the
level of public expenditure devoted to higher education at a constant price was
lower in 2011 compared to 2008. The most severe decline can be observed in
Romania (-36.2%). (European Commission 2015:40-41).
Ultimately, the crisis affects graduates. In the space
of a few years unemployment took on huge proportions especially among the young
including graduates. The policies for overcoming the crisis which have been
followed since 2009 until today began with the acceptance that one of the
fundamental reasons for the crisis was the inflated public sector. For this
reason appointments were ‘frozen’. Thus, the public sector which traditionally
constituted the basic graduate employer ceased to make appointments. The
private sector in turn didn’t compensate for the withdrawal of the public
sector. On the contrary, it was further
weakened during the crisis and didn’t manage to absorb even the relatively
small number of graduates it had absorbed in the past.
The private sector’s inability to absorb graduates
bears witness to the difficulty in the relationship between education and the
economy in Greece. It is also difficult
however to put it down to the quality of training of the graduates and the quality
of the Greek HEIs. On the contrary,
during the crisis more and more young graduates sought work abroad. In summary,
the current developments in Greece raise questions and lead us to rethink the
role of the University more generally.
References
Books
Birnbaum, Robert. (2003). The end of shared governance: looking ahead or
looking back. ERIC.
Bok,
Derek. (2003). Universities in the Marketplace. The commercialization of
higher education. Princeton and Oxford: Princeton University Press.
Clark,
Burton R. (1983). The Higher Education System: Academic Organization in
Cross-National Perspective. Los Angeles, and London: University of
California Press, Berkeley.
Clark, Burton. R. (1995), Places
of Inquiry. Research and Advanced Education in Modern Universities. Los
Angeles, London: University of California Press, Berkeley.
European
Commission/EACEA/Eurydice (2015). The European Higher Education Area in
2015: Bologna Process Implementation Report. Luxembourg: Publications
Office of the European Union.
Eurydice. (2000). Two Decades of Reform in Higher Education in
Europe: 1980 Onwards. Greece, National Description. Brussels.
Friedberg, Erhard and Musselin Christine. (1989). En
quête d’universités. Etude comparée des universités en France et en RFA.
Paris : L’Harmattan
Kant, Immanuel. (2004). Der Streit des
Facultaten. Athens: Savalas editions (translated into Greek by Th. Giouras).
Kerr,
Clark. (1964). The Uses of the University. Cambridge, Massachusetts:
Harvard University Press.
OECD. (2011). Education Policy Advice for Greece. Strong
Performers and Successful Reformers in Education. Paris: OECD.
OECD. (2014). Education at a Glance. OECD Indicators. Paris:
OECD.
Prost,
Antoine. (1997). Education, société et politiques. Une histoire de
l’enseignement en France de 1945 à nos jours. Paris : Seuil.
Readings,
Bill. (1996). The University in Ruins, Cambridge. Massachusetts, and
London: Harvard University Press.
Ringer, Fritz.
K. (1979). Education and
Society in Modern Europe. Bloomington: Indiana University.
Veblen,
Thorstein. (1918). The Higher Learning In America: A Memorandum. On the
Conduct of Universities By Business Men. New York: B. W. Huebsch.
Chapters
in books
Braun,
Dietnar. (1999). «New Managerialism and the governance of universities in a
Comparative perspective», in Braun D., Merrien F.-X. (eds), Towards a New
Model of Governance for Universities? A Comparative View. London and
Philadelphia: Jessica Kingsley Publishers, 239-261.
Duderstadt,
James J. (2014). «Research Universities to Fulfill their Global Promise», in
Weber L. E. and Duderstadt J.J. (eds), Preparing Universities for an Era of
Change. Paris: Economica, 3-13.
Gerbod, Paul. (2004). Relations with
authority. In Ruegg, Walter (general editor), A History of the University in Europe, vol. III, Ruegg, Walter
(ed), Universities in the Nineteenth and
Early Twentieth Centuries (1800-1945). Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press, 83 – 100.
Lockwood,
G. (2011). «Management and resources », στο Ruegg, Walter, (general editor), A
History of the University in Europe, vol. IV, Ruegg Walter, (editor)
Universities since 1945 (1800-1945). Cambridge: Cambridge University
Press, Cambridge, 124-160.
Papers
in Reviews
Boland,
Josephine. A. (2005). ‘Student participation in shared governance: A meαns of
advancing democratic values? Tertiary Education and Management (2005)
11: 199–217.
Holcompe
Randall G. (1997). ‘A Theory of the Theory of Publics Goods’. Review of Austrian Economics, 10 no1,
1-22.
Kiprianos, Pantelis.
(1995). Diplômes et Etat: sur la passion de l'école dans la Grèce
contemporaine. Revue Tiers Monde,
vol. 143 : 598-619.
Lapworth,
Susan. (2004). Arresting decline in shared governance: Towards a flexible model
for academic participation. Higher
Education Quarterly, vol. 58, October: 299-314.
Olson,
Gary A. (2009). Exactly What is ‘Shared Governance’? The Chronicle of Higher Education, July 23. http://chronicle.com/article/Exactly-What-Is-Shared/47065/
.
Electronic
sources
Kiprianos,
Pantelis, Kamarianos, Ioannis, Stamelos, Georgios. and Balias, Sthathis.
(2011). Market and the Higher European educational policies: when the markets
fail-the case of Greece. Revista Educação Skepsis, n. 2, São Paulo, Ιούλιος:
skepsis.org: 61-89, [on line] Available: http://academiaskepsis.org/revistaEducacao.html.
Kladis, Dionyssis. (2012). University governance:
democracy and/or efficiency? Journal
Academia, A Publication of Higher Education Network, vol. 2. No. 1:5-29.
[1] The American Council on Education, and the Association
of Governing Boards of Universities and Colleges “commended” it to their member
organizations.
View Counter: Abstract | 579 | times, and
ACADEMIA | eISSN: 2241-1402 | Higher Education Policy Network
Pasithee | Library & Information Center | University of Patras